0:33 | Intro. [Recording date: May 8, 2014.] Russ: We are recording this episode of EconTalk before a live audience as part of the 33rd Annual Santa Barbara County Economic Summit. Our topic for today is the future of work. As you know, the economy has been sluggish in the last 5 years relative to previous recoveries. The job market in particular has been very disappointing. New job creation has been slow, and most of the reductions in unemployment have come from workers giving up. Some economists worry that this is not a problem of the recovery but a longer term problem that will not go away even if overall economic growth returns to healthy levels. This all takes place against a backdrop of other concerns about the power of technology to eliminate some kinds of jobs--maybe many kinds of jobs, maybe even my job and yours--the long-term decline of manufacturing in the United States, and growing inequality in compensation. And given that depressing introduction, a part of me wants to give up and go back to bed, curl up with a warm cup of cocoa or maybe a shot of scotch. But instead, we're going to hear from three outstanding guests who will perhaps lift our spirits a bit. And if not, make us at least a little bit smarter. Andrew McAfee studies how information technology affects businesses and business as a whole. He is a principal research scientist at the Center for Digital Business, MIT's Sloan School of Management. With Erik Brynjolfsson, he's the author of The Second Machine Age: Work, Progress, and Prosperity in a Time of Brilliant Technologies. Megan McArdle is a columnist at Bloomberg View and has been a correspondent for the Atlantic, the Economist, and Newsweek, an outstanding journalist and pioneering blogger on economic policy. She is the author of The Up Side of Down: Why Failing Well is the Key to Success. Lee Ohanian in the middle is Professor of Economics at UCLA and a Senior Fellow at Stanford University's Hoover Institution. He's an adviser to the Federal Reserve of Minneapolis, and very timely, an expert on economic crisis and recovery. I've asked each guest to give a brief introduction to some aspect of the future of work, what they find interesting. And then we'll sit down and the four of us will have a conversation. We're going to go in alphabetical order. Andy, start us off. |
3:03 | McAfee: Thank you Russ for that introduction. Good morning, everyone. The title of our session today is the Economic Forecasting Project. I actually find economic forecasting just dauntingly difficult, so I'm going to do something that I find a good bit easier, which is a tiny bit of technological forecasting. There are three things that I can say with great confidence are going to continue in the world of technology for the next 10-20 years, easily. The first one is Moore's Law, which as we all, is shorthand for this relentless improvement in computing power, which has been going on for about half a century. The shortest way to think of it is that you get about twice as much computing bang for your buck every 18-24 months, like clockwork, year after year. And you hear--I read in the press once in a while that Moore's Law is running out of steam. Don't believe it. I've been reading that as long as I've been reading about technology, and the best I ever heard it summarized was, I cold-called a really good AI (Artificial Intelligence) researcher at a session like this--his name is Andrew Ng, he teaches at Stanford--and said, 'Andrew, how much more time do we have with Moore's Law?' And he said, 'Five more years, same as the last 30 years.' We've got a lot more time with this relentless improvement in computing power. The reason that's important is that when these numbers get big over time, to the point that--this is not an exaggeration--this is the powerful computer of a generation ago, this is the super-computer of two generations ago. So, when you have this much computing horsepower floating around you can do things you could never, ever do before. The second technological trend that's going to continue is this explosion of data. Big data is an overused shorthand, but it's still an appropriate one. The amount of information in digital form is increasing by many orders of magnitude, very regularly. We're running out of metric system to describe how much data there is out there. None of that is about to stop. And then the third thing that I can say with great confidence is that the geeks of the world--and in my world, 'geek' is a term of deepest praise--are going to continue to take ever-more-powerful computers, and oceans and oceans of data. The reasons the data are important is that data is the lifeblood of science. We just can't get smarter without it. When the geeks take these supercomputers and oceans of data, they bring them together and they turn out innovations that are already astonishing us. And they are going to continue to. So, just in the past few years we've got science fiction into reality technologies, like phones that can understand what we're saying and respond to us and execute our wishes. The world's best Jeopardy player is no longer a person; it's a computer. I rode two summers ago in a car made by Google that drives itself down the highway. These are not science fiction. In many cases we need to keep in mind that George Jetson drove his vehicle to work. Not going to happen for very much longer. The geeks that I talk to say, basically: We ain't seen nothing yet. And over the next 10 years, we're going to take these unbelievably fast computers and oceans of data and we're going to continue to convert science fiction into reality. Heaven only knows where that's going to take us, but the geeks say, Honestly, we are just getting warmed up. So the innovation is absolutely going to continue. Now, I can make two economic predictions based on these technological forecasts. One is, great news. I think it's the best economic news on the planet. The second is a lot more challenging, and it's the topic of our panel today. The great news is what Erik and I, in the book called Bounty--the old joke among economists is that technology progress is the only free lunch we believe in. And that lunch is about to get a lot bigger because of tech progress. So the great news that I can share with you--Russ asked for some glimmers of hope--I have hugely optimistic views about the future, mainly because the big problems that we face are not going to include 'not enough to go around.' I'm the opposite of a Malthusian. I'm a huge cornucopiast about the world we are creating because of technological progress. The challenge, though, is the challenge of distribution. And the other main consequence of all this technology, in addition to bounty, in addition to this great idea of more, is term that Erik and I call 'spread.' And when we wrote the book, and as I've talked about the book, I learned that I've invented the world's dorkiest dance move, because my graphic for spread is me going like this over time. And when you look at wealth or income or social mobility or earnings, or many things that we care about, I find myself doing my dorky dance move over time. Technology is absolutely racing ahead, but it's leaving a lot of people behind as it does so. And this is the great challenge that we as society are going to confront over the next generation, I believe. We found a wonderful quote from Voltaire that I'll end with, and we put it in the book. He said, Work saves us from three great evils: boredom, vice, and need. Of those three, the need is going to be the easiest to take care of, by far, because of this abundant world that we are heading into. How we handle the boredom and the vice of people who want to work but can't find an employer who is willing to take them on, that's going to be one of the huge challenges we confront. I'm sure we'll have a chance to talk about it later this morning. So, thanks very much. |
8:49 | McArdle: Hi. So, I wrote a book about failure and how we process failure, which turns out to be one of the keys to doing failure well. And the biggest surprise I think for me in writing this book was [?] ended up talking about culture and not talking about, you know, aligning incentives correctly with little charts and graphs, but simply about how we process. You can think of culture as the operating system for the hardware that's underneath. Culture is what makes markets work. When you don't have the culture of capitalism, you don't have the culture of bourgeois norms, instead of--we thought when we did Russia, for example, we thought when Russia, the Soviet Union fell, we sent a ton of Western consultants in there to try to teach them how to do capitalism. And we did law. And we did, take away the government and let things fail, because that's what capitalism is, just what Schumpeter called the creative destruction. You let things fail so that bigger and better and more amazing takes its place. The problem was Russia didn't have the culture together, and so Russ actually tells a great story of a guy who shows up in Russia and books a hotel room and the guy just gave him [?]. And [?] says so sue me. If you don't have the culture that says that's wrong, that makes you feel shame about it, capitalism doesn't work. So in Russia, we took away the government, we let things fail, and it's like capitalism, you've got something that's a lot more like a kleptocracy. So, thinking about culture in our own future, because the things that he talks about, these are exciting, amazing things. But they are not exciting and amazing for everyone. We are already seeing this. If you look and you see what is happening down to working class men, and the women that they partner with, or don't partner with, this is a tragedy. It's not just a tragedy in terms of, you know, culture, and in terms of social issues. It's a tragedy in terms of work. Because they raise children who are not prepared to go into the workforce and handle this bounty, handle this cornucopia. Kids who are raised in the partnering system that we are now seeing among the bottom two thirds of Americans who are not raised by educated parents, it's a system where you hook up with someone; after about three or four months you stop using birth control, as a signal that you are really invested in the relationship. You have a child, somewhere between 0 and 5 years after the birth of the child the father will have disconnected from the mother and be with someone else. And that tends to happen two or three times--this is a pattern that we used to see in extremely poor people. It is now the modal means of family formation among people who do not have college diplomas. There's children grow up without the social support, the financial support. One person raising a child by themselves or by a step-parent who is not as invested in the child and is themselves often transitory through the house, is a child who does not get the kind of education that you need to grapple with these issues, the child who does not have, kind of, impulse control that you need to work on these long-term, fairly complex projects. As work has gone away, though, what sociologists say, is, you look at the choices that women are making about single parenthood, and you look at the men that they have available to them, and these men, they are not steadily employed. As Kathryn Edin[?], a sociologist who has done a lot of this work said, if you can get a job at McDonald's and work full time, you are kind of a king in a lot of these inner city areas; but no one can get that job. No one can work full time. This is an enormous challenge. What the computers are doing to retail scheduling. This is great for retailers. Retailers have computers that they look at the weather, they look at demand forecasts from last year, they schedule people and they say go and log in what hours you are available. Computer crunches it all together, and then they spit out a shift. It's great for the retailers. It's a little hard on the workers because you can't even do what you used to be able to do and string two part-time retail jobs together. Because you need to make, say, a block of 80 hours available in order to get 30. Well, you can't do that at two retailers. So what you end up with is someone who can't do the things that we used to depend on for family formation in terms of getting steady, long-term work, that you can predict is going to be there for year after year. That said, sociologists are not thinking about culture. Which is a little strange for a sociologist to be doing. It's very economically deterministic. And in fact my grandfather worked as a grocery boy until he was 26, in the Great Depression. And he was married. He got married at the age of 21, supported a wife for 5 years while he was a grocery boy. And this is not because you used to be able to support a wife and family on the wages that they paid grocery boys back in the good old days. He was making a tiny, tiny, tiny sum. They moved in with his parents. They literally cut a whole in the wall, put their stovepipes through because I believe the Chinese symbol for trouble is two women in one house. Or two women in one kitchen. And so they basically had a tiny, tiny little studio apartment in his parents' house. They paid his parents rent. My grandmother doled out his tiny little salary in an envelope, so much for gas and food; and they lived that way for 5 years. People don't live that way now. That's the culture part. As Brad Wilcox, sociologist at UVA who has studied this a lot, says: People in the Great Depression didn't do this kind of pattern of family formation that we are seeing now. So what we've got is a cycle. And when you talk about this, part of what is contributing to that cycle, part of what is going to contribute to that cycle if we do not intervene, is that people at the bottom with their paths disrupted by work, are not able to sustain a culture of work. So, George Orwell, most of you know him as the author of 1984 and Animal Farm, but before he did that, he wrote amazing sharply-observed books about life at the bottom in 1930s England and France, which I highly recommend to you. He wrote a book called The Road to Wigan Pier where he goes up to the north of England where the coal mines are already winding down, unemployment is enormous, and what he points out is that in an area where most people are unemployed, you can't sustain a norm that you need to have a job. And so when you look at the choices that these women are making, what the sociologists are leaving out is that the men are working intermittently and playing a lot of video games in between, literally. And women are letting them. The women are allowing them to do that and have children with them, without being reliable partners to contribute to those children. If the women demanded more, then the men would provide more. But, the women can't demand more because when 90% of the men in your community can't get reliable work, it's hard to establish a norm that any guy who is not working right now is not pulling his weight and is not a good partner to be romantically involved with. So, that's the sad, depressing future work stuff, where we are not raising the kids who are capable of being the workers that we need. The good news is that this stuff is actually amenable to change, but that we are going to have to make a really conscious effort instead of just thinking deterministically about the economic incentives, to think about the cultural incentives that are being created among people who aren't necessarily going to go to MIT and build robots, but who could have happy, fulfilling lives as workers in the society if we figure out a way to include them, and to include them in a larger culture that everyone in this room shares of what Kathryn Edin calls super-relationships--the best marriages in history. I do think that that's open to more people, that the future of work is open to more people, but we have to be much more conscious about creating that culturally as well as economically. |
16:30 | Ohanian: Good morning. It's a pleasure to be with you today. When we think about the future work, at least what I think about, is how much work will be done, who will work, how will compensation grow, and where will work be located? Now, back in the day, assessing those four trends, one could be pretty confident in making certain predictions. So, for example, back in the day, employment was almost a constant fraction of the adult population. So we could predict how much work could be done--it would be simply employment will grow with the rate of population. And in terms of how that would be compensated, well, that was pretty easy to figure out because for a long, long time the average salary of a worker in the United States would double roughly between the time of their early twenties up through their middle fifties. So workers could anticipate 100% increase in their earnings over the course of their lifetime. And where would work be done? Well, we had areas such as Los Angeles that were major manufacturing areas that were growing at remarkably fast rates. But now all of these trends really have changed. So, in terms of how much work is done, well, very recently we've seen about an 8% drop in employment as a share of the adult population. Where is work done? Well, who would have ever thought that the worst performing metropolitan area in terms of employment growth would be Los Angeles? The last 25 years, Los Angeles has lost 3% in employment[?]. No metropolitan area has done worse. You might be thinking about Detroit. Detroit actually did better than Los Angeles. Detroit lost 1% compared to Los Angeles at 3%. How has compensation evolved? Well, back in the day, technology used to be the tide that raised all boats. All workers' salaries grew with technological change. But today that's much, much different. What's happened is that for highly skilled, highly educated workers, the growth rate of compensation is about 5 times as much as it is for those with high school training or perhaps less than high school training. Let me show you just a couple of pictures to drive home some of these points. This is a picture of the share of the working age population who work, and you can see that it was fairly constant between 2000 and 2007, and the shaded areas are recessions. And you see we fell off the cliff during the recession, but the remarkable amount of work that was being done before the recession hasn't been restored. And we've had a slight uptick here, but we are roughly 9 million jobs below where we would be if we had simply maintained the same employment share that we had in 2006, 2007. Now in terms of who works, we've seen remarkable changes in who works. [Ohanian skips back to continue on the employment share.--Econlib Ed.] This is a picture of our employment share that goes back to 1970. So this puts our decline in relative perspective, and what you'll see is that the decline we've seen very recently is not just a consequence of the recent recession, but really this is a decline that's been continuing for about 20 years. So, the issues that we have in the labor market that Russ talked about really are long term issues, not just a consequence of the most recent recession. Now, in terms of working, the share of women working has increased by more than 50% over the last 50 years, so 40% of women worked, up to about 60% more recently. And that's coincided with a sharp drop in men working. So in 1960 over 86% of working age men were working, and that's down to less than 70% today. So as we go forward, we think about how much work will be done, who will work, how will compensation evolve, there will really be three factors that govern that. Government policies that impact the profitability of conducting economic activity at a particular location such as Santa Barbara or Los Angeles, the United States; globalization which governs who the countries we interact with, we trade with, we learn from; and technology, which governs the efficiency in the way we produce goods and services. And I'll just stop with one last picture, which shows productivity. And the reason we are the richest large country in the world is because we've had technology and productivity growth; it grows about 2% per year, which doubles the efficiency of workers in about 35 years. And the trouble we see is that this is output per hour; and output per hour, the red is the long-run trend of 2% per year, and this squiggly black line which lies below the red is actual output per hour. So our productivity is growing about half the rate over the last 5 years as it has in the past. Now, that's got to reverse if we are going to continue to have a prosperous society. And part of the good news is that the technology will change that Andrew talked about has the potential to raise this substantially and all these factors will get into the panel discussion. And thank you again for coming this morning. |
22:47 | Russ: So, for our first topic I want to talk about the rise of technology that Andy spoke of and his book is about. When we think about technology historically we see that technology has had a big role in displacing physical strength. So, John Henry was a steel drivin' man, but machine comes along, and his great skill then becomes totally unproductive. What we see the glimmers of--and not just the glimmers; it's not science fiction, it's real--we see machines coming now and technology software--Marc Andreessen says software is eating the world. We see machines and technology coming along that seem to be able to replace not just physical strength but intelligence. The driverless car is an obvious example, as you write in your book. Researchers thought it would be impossible, that it would take decades, that it would never be done for a machine to be able to recognize the subtle things that just a simple driver, that we do effortlessly when we drive a car. Well, it's here. That skill, which is a modest skill, is now on its way to being redundant. We see professors, which many of us up here are, being replaced by technology, either by something like Kahn Academy or the rise of so-called MOOCs, Massive Open Online Courses, that may make it impossible for many professors and teachers to make a living. It raises the question: what's going to be left. If strength and intelligence are now taken care of by machines, what are we going to do? Obviously these are just speculative questions. I'd like to start with you, Andy, and talk about how that bounty, which is the result of this technology, might be shared by those of us who are actually spending our time doing productive things. McAfee: So, exactly as you say, 200 years we've been predicting the onset of massive technological unemployment because of the latest round of big new technology that came out. The Luddites smashed looms just about 200 years ago. Marx of course predicted this. John Maynard Keynes wrote an essay in 1930 called "Economic Possibilities for our Grandchildren," where he introduced the phrase 'technological unemployment.' Those folk have all been wrong. And the reason they've been wrong is that essentially, innovators and entrepreneurs come along and think of new needs and new wants to go satisfy out there in the economy, in society. And they employ a lot of people to satisfy those wants and needs. So, the engine of creative destruction, amazingly enough, has been tilted a little bit in favor of creation and away from destruction, when it comes to jobs. So, the question is, if things are different this time, why are they different this time? And the only honest answer any of us can give is: I don't know. My suspicion is they actually are different this time, for the reason you give. We had our power system be largely automated in our organizations, in our tasks, in our jobs for a long, long time. Now the control system is becoming increasingly automated. When both the power and the control are done by machines, what do we need all the human labor for? I honestly scratch my head over that. I don't know. But the critical thing to keep in mind is that the answers to that question are not going to come from the alleged smart people on this stage. They are going to come from this very decentralized activity of innovation, entrepreneurship, capitalism, that we're pretty good at. The only hope we have for putting people back to work and finding more gainful employment is to let that engine do its work. Now, that doesn't mean we need no regulations, capitalism is this fantastic, wonderful thing. My point is that's our only hope for figuring out what all of these people are going to do. Russ: Lee, are you an optimist or pessimist about the future of employment opportunities in a world of artificial intelligence? Ohanian: The trend over the last 30 years, which is really when we started to see the massive increase in technology and information processing has been to substantially improve the productivity of highly skilled people. So, those with the best degrees, college degrees, have benefited enormously from the technology revolution. And as you know, it has really impacted those who don't have those capabilities. My favorite example is in 1950, the ports of New Jersey and New York employed about 10,000 people. Strong guys, longshoremen who picked up a box and brought it to shore, when that ship was empty they filled it back up. Today, [?] 10,000 people works in New York and New Jersey that now move 20 times the load, there's less than 1000 people employed. They are all college graduates that are operating sophisticated forklift, computerized machinery to do all this. So it really has become a situation of sort of haves and have nots. And education is going to be central in terms of allowing workers to benefit from the technology that's available. But one thing I would say is so hard to predict the evolution of these factors. In 1984, AT&T punted on cell phones and gave it to Ameritech because they thought the maximum audience for cell phones would be a million users. Russ: But it slightly, just a titch underestimated the size of that opportunity. Ohanian: Just a little bit. McAfee: There are more mobile phones subscriptions than there are people in the world right now. Russ: Yeah. Which is literally mindboggling. It's incredible. Ohanian: So I think it's just remarkably hard to predict how these things will evolve. I suspect that the greatest computer in the world--there's many of them; they are sitting between our two ears--that we'll still be able to develop technology that makes use of the large [?] of human capital we have in the economy. But again, it's hard to predict how these things will evolve. |
28:46 | Russ: Megan, optimist or pessimist on this question? McArdle: Well, I mean if you don't have power or control, I guess what's left is charm. [?]: We're in deep trouble. Russ: Yeah. Most of us on the panel are. McArdle: I guess my role is the hippy-dippy portion of this program. A friend of mine recently joked that China was taking over a lot of U.S. production to allow us to specialize in what we are good at, which is obviously artisanal pickling. It's a joke but it's also true, that like every Sunday morning I get up and I take my little basket and I walk over to the farmer's market and on the third Sunday every month I go to pick up my meat CSA [Community Supported Agriculture]; and I know the animals have been treated well. [?]: Well, but you don't live in America. This isn't really clearly like that.[?] McArdle: No, this is--or take massages. Like, a massage in 1930 was something that like crazy women in the movies got. Or maybe like boxers would get. It wasn't something where like every pregnant woman in America thinks it's now something you just get a pregnancy massage when they give you the positive test. Okay, go get a pregnancy massage. These services that used to be something that were for the super-elite. And maybe will eventually outsource into robots, but I've tried those Homemedics Mats, and it's really not the same. What people like--what is the most important thing after we've been fed, after we've been sheltered and warm and whatever? What do we like? We like interacting with other people and feeling happy and loved. Right? So, we like feeling people being nice to us, we like feeling special, we like having other people call us 'Miss McArdle' and give us a cup of herbal tea and ask us whether we want our feet massaged. We like all that--maybe not the men in the audience so much. But you guys have golf. That we like those experiences of having other people treat us well. McAfee: But think of your last 10 service interactions with another human being. How many of them left you with that warm, chamomile tea feeling? McArdle: Well, at some level, most of them, actually. Service in America, especially if you've lived abroad, is amazing. In Britain--they practically-- McAfee: That's the wrong benchmark. Terrible benchmark. McArdle: Well, the French, I'm not sure I would put the French up against it, either. Actually, mostly, if it is nice, when you shop, people are nice to me. McAfee: Oh, come on, did you walk through a sea of pleasant experiences in the airports on your way here? If so, I want to travel with you. Russ: That's an outlier. It is an outlier. McAfee: When you call up Comcast, when you go-- Russ: Also an outlier. McAfee: No, no, no. These are the service economy. These are not outliers. Russ: [31:35] No. You've picked the example of the places in America where there is very little competition due to regulation and government monopoly. I mean, there's competition-- McArdle: McDonald's people are very nice to me. Russ: They're cheerful. McArdle: And they ask me if I want something else, and was I satisfied with my order. Russ: Would you like fries with that? McArdle: Emailing me to find out if I liked something that I bought from them that I spent two minutes consuming and never thought about again. Actually I think there's more room for those sorts of things for things like haircuts and things that women didn't used to do. You used to perm your hair at home. My great aunts all permed their hair at home. Now, who would do that? No one would perm their hair, thank God. McAfee: Wait, explain this hair concept? Russ: That's a visual joke, for those listening at home. They'll just have to get the video version. McArdle: More people are getting services provided to them. Even people--you go and you work 10 hours providing hair services and then on the weekend you go and get a massage because you are tired. McAfee: I'm pushing back, but you are absolutely right. One of the weird things that happened in America over the past 30 or 40 years that really no one was anticipating is exactly the rise of these service jobs. And they came on us in huge volume. They have actually helped maintain the wage and the unemployment [employment--Econlib Ed.] levels at the lowest levels of skill and education in the country. The main problem is they are the lowest levels of skill, education, and pay in the country. So great these jobs exist; I completely agree with you. They don't look like ladders toward that classic middle class prosperity in a lot of cases. For exactly the reasons that you outline. McArdle: I think that this is the giant challenge that we face--that we still in a lot of ways maintain the attitude about the service jobs. Part of it is a sheer supply/demand thing: we have a huge oversupply of people who are not [?] by the manufacturing sector, and are transitioning, especially working class men, as I was talking about, they are transitioning very uneasily into the service economy. But that's sad. I mean, lawyers are service people, doctors are service people--there's lots of stuff in the service economy that doesn't have to be low prestige because it's a service job. So partly to go back to the hippy-dippy portion of the program, is that a lot of this is how we treat those jobs and how we view them. Do we say--because, yes, in 1930 if you were a manicurist, the people you were manicuring were extremely rich people and you went home to your cold water flat in Brooklyn. But we don't have to view these jobs that way, and that's a cultural choice that we are making. I think middle class, we're going to have to rethink what the middle class is in this context, and what these jobs mean. But I don't think it's inherently a feature of these jobs that they involve low pay and misery. |
34:26 | Russ: Lee, want to weigh in? Ohanian: This discussion really kind of pushes towards the idea of the jobs that will exist will depend upon what people want. What society wants is going to be produced. And the reason we have so many more of the service sector jobs is because it's getting cheaper to produce these service sector jobs, and because the income is so we now have a lot bigger share of the population can now choose to have a massage or a manicurist than years ago. Russ: It's part of the bounty that technology has given us along the way. Ohanian: It's part of the bounty. Growing at 2% a year means we quadruple living standards every 70 years; but the lifespan now is 80 years. That means children born today, if continued, will see increases their standard of living by a factor of 5. And that's all made possible by technology. Even a 1 percentage point increase, from 2% to 3%, won't be a factor of 5--it will be closer to a factor of 10. So, the possibilities are just enormous. And what it boils down to is: How will that bounty be distributed across different segments of society? McAfee: And Megan's comments bring up a fundamentally important question, is, to exactly your point: How will those benefits be distributed? And when you talk about these lousy service sector jobs, I completely agree with you. If they are going to exist and be a big deal in our economy, how do we turn them into better jobs? And to oversimplify to a huge amount, there are a couple of main levers to do that. One is kind of regulation and fiat and a $15 minimum wage, and you have to treat people at this level. And to the extent I've got any economics thinking in my brain at all, it says, Great, you are baking in rigidities into the process and you are going to scare employers away from those jobs. And they'll automate them more quickly. The other route to that is, you keep talking about hippy-dippy cultural stuff, is to try to change the perception of how we think about those jobs and the pressures we can bring to bear on the stereotypical exploitative employers who pay $9 an hour and make you juggle your schedule around. Do you have any confidence that we can--whether or not it's fair, let's call that a Walmart kind of job. I don't know enough to know how badly they treat their people. But just for stereotype purposes. Do you have any confidence that we can pressure Walmart into behaving differently in that regard? McArdle: Well, I think there is a--so, to start with, I actually think that the money is a problem, but it's not the biggest problem. Because, as you say, there's going to be so much stuff. Right? And the things that money creates a problem with now are kind of artificial scarcity--housing, because it's hard to build, good school districts where you are reshuffling the children around, everyone wants their children with kids who are smarter than their children. And those things, yes, those are a problem, but they would be a problem if people were making $30 an hour. If there weren't any more houses, the bottom of the income distribution would still be living in those houses regardless of how much money they were pulling in. So that actually a lot of those issues are supply side issues. What I do think is--the serious issues are insecurity and the inability to either count on, as you say, understand what your future path looks like, that this is a job that I could actually have for a couple of years, that I can try to build a career and understand what that looks like, that I know I will have this job, that my employer views me as someone that they are not going to fire and let go. The problem is not Walmart in particular. Walmart was always a terrible job, in some ways. It was aimed at housewives and teenagers--that's who they employ. The problem is the other jobs aren't there. So I'm not sure I think it comes from Walmart, because retail is just, in every era that I've been aware of, has been a terrible job. Girls in 1900 New York working in department stores didn't make enough money to live on, and they had--ships--a guy made a ship where it was a dorm for the girls and they would bode out into the harbor every night, because this was the cheapest way to stack them. So, I think the issue is things like manicurists and massage therapists and golf consultants and all of those things--and this sounds really dumb; I know that there are a number of people who are going to be listening to EconTalk, maybe some people in the audience thinking, My God, this is like Marie Antoinette saying 'well, let them eat manicure jobs.' But I think that this is a fact. I'm not happy or sad about it. I just think [?] when you want to compete with a machine, what you cannot [?] is being a person and providing person-like affection and sociability. Russ: People want to chat with their manicurist. And some manicurists like to chat with their customers. There will be a machine that will give you a manicure. The question is, what will be the nature of that interaction that you are talking about, and isn't it going to reward people who enjoy that? We know a bunch of people--we're very unrepresentative, us on the stage. We're way too educated. We don't have a lot of experience of a Wal-Mart cashier. When I'm in a Wal-Mart, which I admittedly shop at occasionally, I'm not ashamed of it, they are happy people. They seem to be enjoying that interaction. I have many friends who do, too, in that they want to sit in their cubicle all day working on their computer sitting in front of a screen, but there are a bunch of people who don't. And they have a different experience. The question is what are they going to be compensated--to me, and is the social consequences of those differences going to be large? Presumably if a lot of people want to sit at a screen and make a lot of money, the fact that being pleasant is a scarce resource, maybe it will get rewarded more generously in the future than we anticipate. McArdle: Well, I was actually the most cheerful cashier at the [?] Pharmacy chain in New York City. People would actually ask me where I was from, on the ground that no one that nice could be from New York. And so one of the things that--who is sociable, who likes taking care of other people--and this is what we've been talking about with the decline of [?]--that's a lot of it. It's that women are willing to do these jobs and they don't mind doing them. There are lots of guys who are good at sales and customer service. It's not like guys are not capable of this. Part of it is that the role we've assigned to masculinity, right, is being gruff and not caring what other people think, and that's not a really very good characteristic for a service job. Russ: That's changing. McAfee: I think Johnny Weir is leading the charge into a different view of that. I for one think that's fantastic. Russ: Who? McAfee: He was the guy wearing the fantastic hat at the Kentucky Derby. Russ: Oh, okay, sorry. Not a Derby guy. I missed out on that. No, but there's no doubt that the cultural factors that, Megan, you are emphasizing, for how we greet and cope with this transition are going to be important. [?]: There's another huge thing in play there, which is that we consumers might not want, might choose to have fewer interpersonal interactions in our day. Russ: We might. [?]: Because the world that's coming is a world where I can go from the airport to the--the car is still going to have a person for a little while--and check in automatically. And I can choose to have many, many fewer interpersonal interactions than right now. And the question I don't know the answer to is: How is the market share going to break down between consumers choosing to go have deliberately interpersonal interactions and the 'just let me check in over here and get my room without talking to a person'. I predict a lot of us who--myself included-- Russ: Correct. [?]: are going to break over that way. Russ: And we're already in that direction. One of the strangest things that we are already--we are already toward the semi-driverless car--is that in the old days, I used to talk to my cab driver. And now, it's culturally acceptable that I don't talk to him. I treat him like a robot, because I'm on my phone. I'm checking my email, surfing the web, answering stuff. And that experience for that cab driver might be better, because he doesn't have to pretend he is interested in talking to you. But again, I think there are people who find that part of the job appealing, and there are people who do like to talk to their cab driver. But many of them, probably you and me, prefer to be on our own. [?]: Definitely you and me. Russ: We are definitely heading in that direction. I want to--yeah, Lee, and then I want to take us to a different direction, topic. Ohanian: I think one issue when people think about, are we going to all lose our jobs because machines are going to become as good as us and they will do it cheaper--technology can be directed toward replacing workers or towards enhancing workers. And the biggest scarcity of constraint most people face is time. And in the example you just gave, I can be on my cellphone in the taxi and I can make progress; I can be productive. That's a great example of a labor-saving device. So you can now make use of time where previously it was gone. Your time in the taxicab about did the Mets win today or not? So technology can be directed, and it will be directed if it's profitable to make people more productive. So it's not as if technology is either we replace people or we have to put brakes on the process of technological change. We can produce technology that enhances our ability to remain productive, remain employed, and produce more business services. McArdle: Look at the Apple store. They employ computers in order to enable these people swarm[?] you and find out what you always dreamed of, in a little tiny laptop or whatever. |
44:10 | Russ: Lee, I want to take your comment and take us in a subtly different direction of how we might, how our culture and our society might evolve to deal with these issues. So you said technology can either enhance or replace, and I like your dock workers story. Follow me on this chain. So you've got 10,000 dock workers; now there's fewer than 1000, and the thousand are how many times more productive, in dollar terms? Is it a hundred times? Ohanian: There are too many zeros for me. Russ: Exactly. So it's many, many multiples of times. Then your next thought is, but somebody's got to make those machines that make those fewer than a thousand workers more productive. But of course those machines are now made by other machines. So, manufacturing in America--it's a secret--is a booming, booming part of economy. It's just not a source of employment. So we make a lot more stuff with a lot fewer people. So you say, well, that can't solve the problem. But then you think, but someone's got to design those really smart machines. And then we get to sort of the real scarcity that gets rewarded, and then you start thinking: Well, how many people can be involved in the creation of machines? And of course there's an enormous move, mainly by people who are already in the field, to encourage kids to learn how to code, to become more computer savvy. Obviously, it's happening; it's not--you don't need a policy change to do that. People are obviously growing in their ability to do that. So I want to shift just to education. Let's talk about where we think the education system might be heading. What's holding it back that will let people prepare for perhaps a very different world? Megan, what are your thoughts on that? McArdle: I think that one of the problems with education, and one of the problems with health care, is that unlike other issues, you stick a person in one side of the system and they come out the other; and they get a good job, they live or die if they go into the hospital. And it's hard to know if it's because you took someone who was conscientious and hard-working and really bright, or because the system is good. And so, one of the things that you see--even in the old line unions like the Operators Union is that they are desperate for people. Because they need people who can do high school math. And those people go to college, and they don't want to be operators. These are good jobs; they pay really well, great benefits, better than a lot of college students who are ending up in Starbucks. But the college student who ends up in Starbucks, they want the option value of being a college graduate and so they never become an operating engineer. And so you see this in a lot of these unions that require skilled workers is that they can't get them because nobody wants to do blue collar work. And at the same time, people are working in Starbucks and waiting for their big break, as some sort of white collar worker. Can we produce more people who are good at high school math? It's hard to know. When you look at these studies, it's really discouraging. It's discouraging how little early childhood intervention do; it is discouraging how badly a child who goes into a high-poverty school does and how low the graduation rates. And how nothing we have done in 30 or 40 years barely budges the [?] and when we do find someone, it's usually a good principal or good collection of teachers who make a difference; we can't replicate it. I believe that there are great principals who can make a difference. I also believe that there doesn't seem to be a way to teach others how to be that great principal. And so, I think that education, if we could educate people in the way that we would ideally like, would help. On the other hand I would also say that there is kind of a myth of the STEM shortage. Russ: STEM being science, technology, engineering, and mathematics. McArdle: Is that in fact, you look for example at pharmaceutical researchers. These guys were getting devastated by all the layoffs in pharma. And nonetheless, there are lots of kids being encouraged to get a major in chemistry because that's a great job to have when you get out. In a lot of fields there doesn't actually seem to be an undersupply. A lot of the undersupply that you see in all of these fields is that the employer who is competing with China can't afford to pay what people want in order to bring their skills to that employer. And so, what we don't have exactly is mismatch--what we have is a mismatch between people who want to make $40,000 a year and be a highly college-educated chemist for a company and that's what they can afford to pay and compete with China. It's really, really tricky. Russ: Lee. Ohanian: For our generation, I think, public education worked pretty well. We had a foundation where we could go out and succeed if we had the ambition and we tried hard. I think that for a large number of children today, that's a more difficult challenge. And when you look at international comparisons across student achievement, it's depressing. Only about one third of our kids are what's termed as proficient in science and math. And it's not a particularly high bar. Compared to 70% proficiency rates in Japan and Korea. And in our poorest states such as Mississippi or New Mexico, proficiency rates are comparable to Croatia and Kazakhstan, very poor countries that just don't have the resources to develop or to devote to education. So, we have to make substantial changes in the quality of education. McAfee: And do you have a good sense of why the wheels came off some time between when you were getting educated and today? Ohanian: There's been a lot of research done on the impact to teachers and the quality of teachers. So, our colleague at Stanford, Rick Hanushek, has done some research looking at the impact of teachers and what would happen if, say, the poorest-performing teachers were taken out of the classroom and what you put back in was roughly the average quality. And the results are remarkable. So, for example, just for kindergarten: the importance of a good kindergarten teacher compared to a poor kindergarten teacher, about $400,000 in terms of lifetime income. In terms of providing a foundation to a motivated child to get them on the path of learning. And I think one aspect of education that sometimes is not discussed enough is that to allow us to succeed in the world we have today and the type[?] world we'll have tomorrow is we have to be adaptable. We have to be able to learn new tasks, new activities. And rote learning which is sometimes common in our education system is exactly the wrong approach. Rote learning means you cannot be creative, you can't adapt, you can't learn new things. So teacher reform I think is a major issue. I think more and more people are understanding that increasing competition in schools is an important factor. And I hope you see that as we go forward. Russ: Andy. McAfee: Your story reminds me--I was on stage a while back debating with Peter Thiel, who is a legendarily good venture capital, investor, entrepreneur, and he's got some fairly [?] ideas; but he said something that I found really interesting. He said, We all agree that critical thinking is an incredible important skill for people to have. I don't think anyone who thinks they are teaching critical thinking, who labels what they are doing critical thinking, is actually doing anything like teaching critical thinking. So the question then becomes exactly how do you instill these kinds of skills that you are talking about, this flexibility, this ability to learn new stuff over the course of a career or a life? This is a great big deal. My really unscientific, idiosyncratic answer is: I was a Montessori kid, and I'm so grateful for that experience, because it really did teach me that the world is an interesting place and my job is to go poke at it. There's a thing called the Montessori Mafia in the high-tech industry; it turns out that Jeff Bezos of Amazon, both of the Google founders, Jimmy Wales of Wikipedia--these people were all Montessori kids. So I think there is something about that early childhood flavor of, this hippy-dippy educational system that means something. But let's go test that with data. Like you say, your colleague and [?] have done amazing work to help us understand how bad a bad teacher is and how much better even an average teacher is. They did that because we have data over a long period of time on these issues. Let's continue to gather the data. With education, there is no shortage of theories about what works. There's a big shortage of really serious data and research about what's worked out. So let's turn the dial up on that. Russ: Yeah. The real question is, is it really the case that Andrew McAfee, Sergey Brin, and Jeff Bezos were transformed by the Montessori school-- McAfee: And we would all have been hopeless wrecks without it. Russ: Exactly. It's hard--well, I say it--not only is it hard to know, it may be impossible to know. The data is very difficult to use in a way that would allow us to tease that out. McAfee: I don't think we have enough separated-at-birth identical twins. Russ: That's the problem. McAfee: One of whom went to Montessori and one-- Russ: Exactly. McArdle: We could fix that model--get some identical twins. McAfee: That's social engineering for you. |
53:20 | Russ: So let's--we all agree that the education system could do a better job. I think the challenge is: How do we get there from here? And Lee, you mentioned more competition, better teacher quality. What are your thoughts on how we might have a better education system for preparing people for that world of work? In particular, is it really--how important is it? I like to think about the fact that we have states where people are being educated the equivalent of some very poor countries. And yet somehow, we do pretty well. And I think the reason we do pretty well is there is a small number of people who manage to transform the world and lift us up--those are the Andrew McAfees, Jeff Bezoses of the world. McAfee: And we're magnets for the smart, tenacious entrepreneurial people from all around the world. Russ: Yeah. So, if education does make a difference, and I'm somewhat skeptical--Rick Hanushek has been a guest on EconTalk and talked about that work and defended it--but I'm somewhat skeptical of that transformative power, because we see so many other things going on. But to the extent that it is, what are the key things that we ought to be doing to let that happen or to cause it to happen? Ohanian: When you look in the classroom now--you and I have gone through secondary school, post-secondary school, graduate programs--I think what we see is how important peer-group learning is, peer group effects are. A big difference between when we went to school and I think school now is that class size has gone up from 20 when we were kids, up to 30 and perhaps higher in some schools. And as you get large class sizes, you have a breakdown of peer effects, because the chance of having a disruptive kid or more than one disruptive kid is much higher. And from the standpoint of research on peer effects, having that continued as a smooth process through primary school and secondary school is, my guess is that that can be very important. As opposed to kids that are sitting in the classroom saying, I'm not getting stimulated; I'm not really seeing what's being talked about; the kid next to me is being disruptive. And then you start to lose a kid. So, as you point out, research is difficult in this area because control groups are hard to come up with. Based on my own observation teaching for 20 years, I think of peer effects as being incredibly important. Russ: But when you talk about rising classroom size, in the public schools of America, for a long time the trend was smaller. The teachers' unions fought, argued--I think incorrectly, but you are sort of disagreeing--that smaller classroom size was the key to better education. Which of course was a way to justify increasing size of the number of teachers on staff. Two issues to think about. One, I think we tried that experiment; it didn't work very well, as far as I can tell. Let's say it differently. There's no evidence that it worked well. But the next thing I think about is the move toward technology, toward the virtual classroom, certainly gets rid of those peer struggles that get those peer benefits--you are talking about you are sitting in the classroom with 150,000 people around the world, with the best professor in the world, but you are not interacting in the way that you used to in a great classroom before. [?]: No, that's only one option for how you do massive open online education. Another option is that you would go listen to that superstar teacher and then come together in a physical space with peers. Russ: With a coach. [?]: Maybe with a coach. Flip the classroom that way. So I don't believe it's an either/or choice at all. What I do believe is that the technology does give you access to these superstar educators, does give you the ability to personalize the education so if the kid's not getting polynomials, you can back up and throw more polynomials at her. And it also instruments the whole process so we start getting huge amounts of data about what's working and what's not. [?] bravo. Russ: Yeah. Megan. McArdle: I think the possibility that is one of the really exciting places, that technology can pinpoint exactly where you are failing. Video games are really good at that. It used to be that you had to play 97 levels of Donkey Kong to get to the point where you were going to fail again. And now you stop, you go back to the same point just before you died. And my husband does this a lot. McAfee: You married one of those dropout guys that as you say just plays videogames? McArdle: No. Actually, he writes about video games. Which is-- Russ: So it's [?]. At least [?]. McArdle: [?] the stereotypical geek-think family. But you go back to the point right before you died and you try again. And that's incredibly powerful. You just go right to where you failed and figure that thing out rather than having to re-run the entire lesson. Or, if you're a smart kid, sit there while everyone else takes three weeks figuring out polynomials. But that said, it has to be done well. And that's the hard part. Yes, I think that good teachers probably matter a lot. But finding good teachers, it's not correlated with anything that we can study. We don't know, it's not education, Teach for America doesn't seem to have great results, and so forth. Finding those teachers, getting them in the classroom, keeping them in the classroom--that's really difficult. Especially because we've seen over the last 50 years is the ability, this increasing class segregation of American schools. And so, the automobile really gave, first affluent, and then middle class and lower middle class parents the ability to pull themselves away from poor kids, and so watching one disruptive kid, there are districts in Baltimore and D.C. where the teacher would be thrilled to have one or two disruptive kids. Where you have high-poverty districts, where you may not be getting enough to eat at home, Mom or Dad may have a drug problem; Dad may not be there, he may be in prison. Those kids, the issue is not that we don't have a top-quality teacher in there. There's like a lot of issues that have to be addressed first when you have a classroom you can't control. Which is what the teachers report. You can't keep a good teacher there, because it's draining and horrible, and they want to go to a school district where there are kids that will at least listen when they talk and they don't have to be drained every day doing it. And so the kids who need it most, the kids are getting completely left behind, and more and more of them as these working class school districts start to look like very poor school districts did, that those people are the least likely to get all of this stuff that we do. I was a Montessori kid, too-- McAfee: Ha! See! McArdle: and I assume that without it I would probably be living on the streets of New York City right now, panhandling for change. But I also had two upper middle class parents who read to me a lot, and cared a lot about my education. Russ: Causation is a complex thing. McArdle: Yeah. It's really difficult. |
1:00:21 | Russ: Is it possible that the so-called STEM fields can absorb a lot more people? Or is just that they are a lot more difficult? They pay a lot. One of the reasons people want to keep encouraging so-called STEM learning--science, technology, engineering, and math--is that they pay well. But I worry it's a little bit like saying, 'We need more NBA basketball players.' They have a high salary. That's not the road to prosperity. There's an inherent scarcity, as we know on this panel, of tall people. McArdle: I don't know what you're saying, Russ. Russ: For those of us who are below the median, that strategy is not a productive one. So--let's do this briefly because I have an important issue I want to turn to before we run out of time--is it possible, with a great school system, to get more kids into these technological fields, or is it just that it's hard to do and there aren't enough people who can do it well? McAfee: I refuse to believe that we've plateaued in our ability to put people through a STEM education. Like you know, early in the last century, people thought that the idea that everybody could get a college education was ludicrous. There are just morons in society; we couldn't get there. We didn't plateau then; I refuse to believe we've plateaued now. Russ: Quick answer, Lee. Ohanian: We're a math-phobic society. And if we make progress on that, we'll get more people who are competent in math and science. McArdle: I feel like this panel, I'm going to push back a little bit, which is that everyone on this table passed calculus, right? There are a lot of people who can't even get to the point where they are prepared to [?] calculus. But that said, I think one of the questions is can we get them through? The other question is: If we get them through, will the jobs still pay as much? Russ: They won't. That's okay. McArdle: One of the reasons STEM pays well is--they won't but that's really a challenge for people who are in the field now and for people who are thinking about doing it, because STEM--I was an English major, and then I went and got an MBA (Master of Business Administration) at Chicago, and I have to tell you, being an English major is a lot easier than doing math. So, if the pay isn't high, are people going to want to push through? Russ: Well, that's okay. I just want to close this segment and just mention that we are talking about, to some degree, engineering and the education system, how we ought to tinker with it. My view is that we ought to get out of the way. We have a big problem. The big problem is that our education system is very rigid, very uncompetitive, and persists in putting, whether it's 15 or 30 people, in little desks in front of a teacher, and we need to let a thousand flowers bloom. We need to see some experimentation, we need flipped classrooms, we need apprenticeships and other things; maybe not everybody should go to college. We need a lot more adaptability and flexibility for these changes. And I suggest that our system is not very well designed for that, and we ought to be breaking down the things that keep that from happening. |
1:03:25 | Russ: I want to close with an issue that--we've been talking about some very grand--and it's fun, I wish we had 2, 3 hours, we could keep going. But I want [?] something a little more short run. We've been talking about sort of long run issues, about culture and education. In the short run, it also appears that our system doesn't work so well. So, Lee made the point that a lot of the problems that we are seeing right now may be symptomatic of longer, bigger problems. But we have some short run problems. Our labor market doesn't seem to be as flexible as it once was, in that creative destruction process. And it's not just these big, grand issues of technology and matching people, etc. It just seems that the labor market is not functioning the way it did 10 years ago, 20 years ago, in response to a downturn. So, one worry that people have is that we are becoming a little more like Europe. Andy, you mentioned the cry for a higher minimum wage. It just recently failed to pass the Senate, but there's a lot of support and pressure for that kind of thing--among economists, even. These rigidities that you mentioned, do you see them as important? Are there rigidities we ought to be trying--are there policy changes we ought to make, to make our labor market and job market more flexible? So, talk about that short run issue. Andy, why don't you go first. McAfee: Yeah, there are probably too many, too much regulation in place. There are too many rigidities. It's actually not at the top of my list. It's absolutely on my list, but there's stuff that I would put much, much higher on the short term playbook that we should be engaging in. In the book, Erik and I talk about the Econ 101 playbook, just to convey this idea that there are very simple macroeconomic things that we should be doing that we're doing a pretty poor job of right now. And my mnemonic for them is--I have the "Old McDonald" theme song running in my head--it's EIEIO. We should be doing a better job on entrepreneurship, on infrastructure, on education, on immigration, and then the 'O' is original research, or basic research. You'd have to go very far left or very far right before you find a well-trained economist who would disagree that government has a role to play in all these 5 areas. We're doing a mediocre to actively lousy job in all those 5 right now. Russ: We could stop right here because there's not that many times I think in the 33 years of this Summit, or the 400-plus episodes of EconTalk, that someone's invoked 'eieio', and I feel like--it's pretty special. I would have preferred it be sung rather than recited, but that's okay. McAfee: Not by me, you wouldn't. Russ: Give me a couple of examples of what we are doing badly and what we should be doing better, say, in entrepreneurship or immigration. McAfee: Immigration is just so easy, right? Like I said earlier, we have the world's most ambitious, tenacious, dedicated entrepreneurial people begging to come here, and we've put these Kafkaesque hurdles in their way. At every level, from education to H-1B visas. Other countries have made progress in getting a startup visa in place. If I were designing a way to hamstring economy I could not do better than what we are doing with immigration policy right now. Russ: Lee, do you want to react to that immigration and also weigh in on this issue of what might we be doing to make the labor market more effective? Ohanian: So, I did some calculations recently. I wanted to see how workers who lost their jobs in the most recent recession, how they fared when they became re-employed. And these are people that are getting jobs after they lost a job in 2008 or 2009. And the median person is taking a 35% pay cut. Just enormous. So, their wage is going from about $19 an hour down to about $12 an hour. And when you look at that--and this is something that's very new. So when I went back in time, and this is not something you saw in, say, the 1991 recession or the 1973-1974 recession. People who became reemployed, became reemployed at a wage pretty close to what they were earning beforehand. Russ: But a sizeable number are often earning more, just by good luck or something [?] Ohanian: Yeah. And when we looked at these large wage changes, I can't help but think about the fact that new business creation in the United States is down by about 35%. And when we think about economic growth, the process of economic growth, it's not the General Motors and IBMs of the world, the big job creators. They employ a lot of people, but they won't have any more people working for them 5 years from now than they will today. They'll probably have fewer people working for them 5 years from now. It's--the question becomes: Who is the new Amazon? Who is the new Intel? Who is the new Microsoft? Who is the new Apple? And the 35% drop in new business formation is just a tragedy. And this is comparing even the good years of 2004, 2005, 2006 to, say, the 1980s and 1990s. And so when I think about economic policy, I agree with Andy completely about immigration. As economists we always say there's no free lunch. There's a free lunch I think when it comes to immigration reform that brings in skilled workers, because half, I think it's that half of all high-tech startups, of all successful high-tech startups, are founded or co-founded by an immigrant. And the problem is so [?]-- McAfee: And that number is going down. For exactly the reasons you identify. Ohanian: And the problem is so acute in Silicon Valley that there's a company called BlueSail[?] that's going to buy, that's buying an ocean liner and they are going to dock it 12 miles offshore, where international waters start; and it's going to be home to about 2000 entrepreneurs who can't get visas. And they will live on this boat and they'll get in a little dingy and they'll go in to land and get in a taxi and go to Silicon Valley. Incredibly inefficient, but these people want to be here; they want to start new businesses; we make it very difficult for them. So I think that is--and there are bills now, proposals in both the House and the Senate to make these changes. So I think we might get some progress on this [?]. And then, tax reform I think is fundamentally important. Russ, you talked about our looking more like Europe. In the state of California if average up or aggregate tax rates with Federal, state, and local, for the highest earners, many of whom are entrepreneurs, that number comes to 60%. So in other words, you earn an extra dollar, you can buy about 39 cents of extra stuff with that extra dollar you earn. And those are Western-Northern-European level tax rates. And there's less work being done today in Western, Northern Europe than in 1950. That's not correcting for population growth. That's just flat out less work being done. McAfee: You mean number of hours per-- Ohanian: Number of hours worked. McAfee: Really? Ohanian: So Germany's considered to be the economic success for Europe. Hours worked per adult is down about 40% in Germany, relative to what it was in 1960; it's down about 35% in France. All of those countries have dropped between 30 and 40%. So I think Europe's run the experiment for us, and tax rates at that level are very damaging. So I would say immigration reform and taxes are two areas we'd make progress on. Russ: Before I ask Megan to comment, that drop in re-employment salary--you suggest that it was caused by a lack of new business formation. Are you suggesting that that's being driven by much higher tax rates than we had, say, in 1973 or 1990? They were pretty high then, too. Ohanian: Yeah. I think there's a number of factors behind new business formation. I think taxes are one part of the story; it's not the whole part of the story. And when I try to connect, drop in salary to new business formation, it's the fact that job growth is--where it occurs is small businesses--we don't have as many as we should compared to the past. So I think there's not as many opportunities for people who are--there's not as many $20-an-hour jobs out there as there would be if we had more new businesses. McAfee: And the regulatory thicket confronting a prospective enormous seems to be getting denser and denser over time. Ohanian: I think it's maybe the most important question that we have entrepreneurs here in the audience--is it just taxes and regulation, or is it the case that there was something very special about the 1980s and 1990s that gave us those kinds of numbers? And I think we just don't have the data or the record of experience to discriminate between those two. Russ: I'm a little more optimistic, because I see, to me, there are a lot of regulations but it would seem that technology is making it a lot easier to start a business. [?]: The flip side of that, though, is that technology is also going to make it easier to grow your business without hiring a lot of people. Russ: True. This is true. Megan. McArdle: This is amazing, right? You look at GM (General Motors) at the height of its power as a company--it put half a million people, over 300,000 people on their line in 1950. They made half the cars on the American road; they were the envy of the world. People forget this about GE[?], it was an amazingly innovative company for decades. And then you look at Google--it was a fraction of the number that GM did. Facebook, Twitter, all of these huge-growth companies, which is where--small businesses create a lot of jobs; they also destroy a lot of jobs. So where do you get the job growth? You get the job growth from the company that starts small and gets bigger. Those companies are happening, not as much as they should; but when they get bigger they are just not hiring nearly as many people-- McAfee: But we have to look outside the high-technology, the software industries. They are totally atypical in the productivity per employee. McArdle: Right, I think that's exactly right, and I think this goes back to what Russ said, which is that, it's true that in the high-tech industry, you bootstrap it with a couple of people and the regulatory thicket is minimal. On the other hand, you talk to people who--I talked to one guy, this is a super-liberal guy--decided to start a business. Had issues because of the financial crisis, but said ultimately what did him in was that his inability to know whether he was in compliance with the regulations. He said, the payroll tax people who handle his [?], he also does his payroll, they'd just like tack on a $200 fee and be like, you have to pay this. He has no way to know. He has a Ph.D. in economics; he's not a dumb person. He has no way of knowing whether this is correct; he has to take it on faith. And this is true. And especially then when you drill down to a business that has any sort of environment impact, that is in an area like Seattle, that wants to raise your minimum wage to $15--these are huge considerations. My basic deal about this is that the United States needs a regulatory budget. Which is that every time you want a new regulation, you've got to take another one away. Because these things--you have two things, it's pretty easy to think how they interact. When you have 2 million, the number of potential interactions is beyond any human brain. And that is the key problem in labor mobility, I would say is the other big one that hasn't been mentioned, which is there are jobs in North Dakota, and people from West Virginia are not moving to take those jobs. |
1:14:45 | Russ: And that's--the interesting question there is whether that's because there are information challenges or we've created some government policies that make it pleasant to stay where you are, too costly to move. We're out of time. I want to take two minutes to finish up here. We talked about a lot of depressing things, today, a lot of challenges, a lot of problems that we have. I want to close--each take 30 seconds and tell me whether you are an optimist or a pessimist going forward about the future of work in America. We'll finish this. Andy, you can go first. McAfee: I'm a pessimist about work as we are currently defining it. When I look out--I'm in my mid-1940s--in my lifetime I'm going to see a labor-wide[?] economy of an abundant society just won't need that many people doing jobs. If we play our cards right, we can make that a utopian version of science fiction as opposed to a dystopian one. But the choices that we make starting now are going to figure out which one of those trajectories we go down. Russ: Lee. Ohanian: I'm an optimist. I think we will figure out a way to get better government policies to make the United States a more competitive place to do business in. I think we will figure out--people will demand to see changes in schools that will prepare, that allow kids to be competitive; and I think we'll see technological change that will be in some part directed towards individuals to make them more productive. There's a lot of people in the world; they want to work, and that's a big, big incentive to produce technology that allows them to be productive. Russ: Megan. McArdle: Short term pessimist, long term optimist. I think the Luddites were right about machines. They were terrible. If you were an artisanl weaver and a machine came along that could do your job and produce 10 times as much as you did--most of the people who went out against the machines probably never had it as good in their lifetimes as they had before the machines came along. And so I think when you have machine change, you have people who are displaced. And it's all very well to say, Retrain. But people can't. Colonel Sanders didn't start selling Kentucky Fried Chicken until he was 65. And he only did it because his business failed. So it isn't that you can't. But it gets harder. The older you are, the prospect of saying, I'm going to go back to school for 4 years and retrain to do something else in your mid-1950s starts to look like not a very good investment. So, there are people who are going to be displaced, and we are going to have to figure out how to handle them culturally, institutionally, policy-wise. On the other hand, in the long run, I think that people do. We're not going to know how it's going to come. But the market will invent stuff for those people to do. And they will do it because people like the esteem of the people around them. They like feeling useful. This is the thing that really shows through in the research on unemployment. It's like the worst thing that can happen to you in a Western democracy, short of death or dismemberment. You never get over it. Five years after you lost your job, you are still almost as miserable as you were. And this is in Germany, which had a very generous unemployment benefit. It's not the money. It's the disconnection. We'll find something for those people to do that will be reciprocal and embed them in society in the way that work has always done for people. But I don't know what it is and I think it's going to take some time to figure out. Russ: Yeah. My optimism. I'm also an optimist, and I'll close by saying that Adam Smith once wrote that there's a lot of ruin in a nation. Meaning that we make a lot of mistakes but we can often overcome them. And I think we often understimate. As I think we all hinted at or said explicitly here today, the role of technology, markets, and culture that is not controlled by anyone but that evolves to cope with change--and I think we're very good at that in America; I think we'll continue to be good at it. |
READER COMMENTS
S
Jun 2 2014 at 12:49pm
Megan added the most value by far. She was the only one that seems to understand natural human ability, and that there are limits to what any of us can achieve. Her points about culture were amazing.
Lee pointed out that economists see high skilled immigration as a free lunch. He could have gone further.
Everyone seems to see the connection between new tech and more-automation/fewer jobs, and then they started talking about high-tech entrepreneurship and seemed to forget about the first 90% of the conversation.
John
Jun 2 2014 at 2:49pm
Ms. McArdle has a bit of a blind spot when it comes to discussing culture. What about her culture? The culture of two income professionals who decide having children just does not fit in with their dynamic, intellectual lifestyle? The very people that have the financial and social means to raise the next generation of innovators and leaders have decided that it is just too much of a bother.
I do not have insight into her personal situation, but in my work I interact with many from her strata. And invariably they have either zero or just one child. This deserves as much commentary as the failed parenting culture of our poorer communities.
Jessease
Jun 2 2014 at 3:25pm
The roundtable was interesting in that it allowed for more input on the topic. However, it seems to me that not much attention was paid to the long-term possibility that a significant amount of labor may disappear (sooner than later) and what the consequences or solutions might look like. I like the idea that we may innovate our way out of it and give people things to do, but I don’t see that occurring within a free-market economy as many libertarians want.
I personally see job destruction through automation as a good thing and that many of the tasks people endure during their work day are a waste of time and energy. The problem is that when you mix declining human labor with our winner-take-all capitalist framework, you end up with rampant poverty. Concepts like ‘a living wage’ do not exist in the free-market vocabulary.
We are currently on a path where declining jobs will likely continue to persist. It is a very complicated and difficult social issue to deal with especially in our global landscape. We seem to be taking a ‘hope for the best’ approach towards dealing with one of the biggest problems of our time. I agree with McAfee that the choices we make today will likely influence if the outcome is more positive or negative. We can’t make much progress towards a solution unless we seriously discuss the real possibility of a future with less jobs.
GG
Jun 2 2014 at 4:52pm
Interesting episode. I have three comments:
1. The part about the smiling Walmart employees, implying they smile all day and chat because they are happy, seems at least disingenuous. I wonder if any of the panelist really have close friends or family members, maybe single moms, who need to work in those type of service (smiling required), low paying jobs all day forced to smile for fear of a bad review and consequent firing.
2. I see the fact that German workers work less than they did and they have a better lifestyle a success policy, not a negative. Is the goal in life to work more and more hours as smiling Walmart employee for $8/hour?
3. If taxes are so bad (60% in CA), why are states with right to work laws, incentives for companies and low taxation such as Mississippi some of the poorest in the country? ND success is transient. When the energy boom will be over, I wonder if unemployment will remain at 3%.
anonman
Jun 3 2014 at 1:00am
I’ve always wondered, as a largely self-taught person in music, specifically trumpet-playing, why we even need teachers sometimes.
This is a real question.
The best programmers often come from universities, but they often don’t as well.
If I were to have my way, the best thing for myself, being interested as I am in programming, would be freedom from constraint and stress in learning it.
You shouldn’t tell people that if they don’t learn it, they will be poor.
The video on youtube of what motivates us is highly informative in this regard. It’s by RSA animate. The paradox is that physical labor is motivated by money, but not knowledge work. Knowledge work is paradoxically encouraged by less money and the strive for self-mastery.
The best thing society could have done for me in my youth is to, wait for it…….have no teachers at all, at least at times.
Knowledge is best guided, but not forced into people. Teachers can provide a skeleton that makes your ultimate understanding faster and more comprehensive, but they will not instill in students keen insight learned from trial and error and the student will not have the knowledge in the gut.
That’s my proposal. Forget teachers. It’s a highly, highly radical solution, but one that I don’t hear ever, and is legitimate.
Just let kids do what they want and if they see a real reason to learn and understand why they are learning it, they will teach themselves.
So, yeah, build me a private school with few teachers and real carrots, like a robot that is already built for demo, but you have to teach yourself how to build it. I want to see this in action, like yesterday.
Jerm
Jun 3 2014 at 5:50am
Good news, anonman!
Your idea is radical, but it’s over 100 years old. Professor Hill has been using a very similar system that he developed at the Gary Conservatory of Music (class of 1905).
But even in today’s world, there’s a lot of people who have gone down the exact path you describe.
If you mean to “forget teachers” after high school, then that would describe a sizable percentage of the US population as is. And all of them could learn programming or economics or whatever interests them, with all of the resources of the internet.
If you mean to “forget teachers” after middle school, then there’s still a good chunk of the US population who fit that description. And looking worldwide, there’s a large percentage of the population who have this exact level of formal education.
If you mean to “forget teachers” in primary education, there isn’t so many in the US who fit this description today, but there were in older times. And there’s a lot of the world who receives this level of formal education today. All of them can use trial and error and intellectual curiosity to learn without the structure of formal education.
Private schools “with few teachers and real carrots” might describe a lot of the world. And with the large diversity of home-schooled students in the USA, I would think that some of them would surely fit this description.
Steven
Jun 3 2014 at 4:30pm
I am familiar with several of the guests on this program. The overall impression I got from the panel, for the long-term, was to be reminded of what I call a “Star Trek future.” Anyone familiar with Star Trek knows that work is not necessary because technology has advanced to the point that all basic needs can be met at zero marginal cost. The citizens of the Star Trek future work because they want to work. The crew of the USS Enterprise get their kicks out of exploring the galaxy, and while they’re at it they also protect Earth from existential threats such as Klingons, Romulans and The Borg. As an aside, would it be fair to say that the Klingons represented the Russian threat, Romulans the Chinese threat, and The Borg a sort of Big Brother threat?
Okay, so what do we do in the meantime, before the Star Trek future, since providing for the basic needs of people is far from zero marginal cost? As long as people still need decent jobs to enjoy a decent standard of living, what do we do?
The most memorable idea came from McAfee when he mentioned the Old McDonald song, EIEIO, a mnemonic for entrepreneurship, infrastructure, education, immigration, and original research. As always, I’m interested in the details. The book that McAfee and Brynjolfsson wrote, “Race Against the Machine,” does not offer any kind of blueprint for a new economic model.
Steven
Jun 3 2014 at 5:14pm
GG, I like your points. Regarding Mississippi, the concessions you mentioned were necessary for that state to attract business. What else did Mississippi have to offer?
Depending on one’s perspective, such things can be seen as good or not-so-good. Take Texas: Rick Perry accurately boasted that Texas created 40% of the nation’s new post-crisis jobs. But he didn’t bother to mention that all of those new jobs were not enough to keep up with population growth in that state, which means that the unemployment rate in Texas went up, not down. He also didn’t mention that Texas is tied with Mississippi for the highest percentage of minimum wage workers.
I’m sorry to say that the majority of the “discussions” about political and economic issues is wasted on gross simplifications, superficial talking points and half-truths (not to mention outright lies and distortions). Decent programs like EconTalk could certainly replace media stalwarts such as NBC’s Meet The Press, CBS’s Face The Nation, and ABC’s This Week.
Evan Downie
Jun 3 2014 at 8:32pm
I am an avid listener, and fan, of EconTalk. Because of this I felt compelled to write a short review of this episode.
Not my favourite (please excuse the Canadian spelling of “favourite”).
Andrew
Jun 3 2014 at 8:56pm
So, about 8 minutes in, McArdle says:
I was amused that the transcription includes question marks in the same place where I was unable (after multiple listens) to determine what she said.
As far as thoughts on this episode, I think the future is pretty scary. I’m 30, I finished undergrad and earned a Master’s degree, and even with that level of education the job I trained for mostly disappeared within 5 years of my graduation, and I ended up having to change careers completely to make a living.
I was lucky in that one of my hobbies (programming) is highly commercially viable. Most don’t fall into that category. I know a large number of people around my age who completed good “practical” degrees from well-known universities and who have spent years trying but unable to find a job with any potential as a long-term career.
I’m not sure this can be fixed. We’ve got more people coming out of college than we have demand for college educated workers, and what I see in my life experience is that we’re getting further behind. We’ve got an entire generation of people who are largely underemployed and are unlikely to ever catch up economically to where they aspired and expected to be.
The real irony of this is that today’s underemployed young adults are also going to be coerced to fund the increasing burden of providing welfare via social security and medicare to the generations that came before them, even though those generations had far greater economic opportunity. Regressive intergenerational wealth redistribution could be as big a problem as any America faces over the next 30 years.
Steven
Jun 4 2014 at 1:07pm
Andrew wrote: “The real irony of this is that today’s underemployed young adults are also going to be coerced . . .”
Andrew, I’ve heard this so many times and I feel compelled to say something about it. Why use the term “coerced”? Were the parents of all these young adults “coerced” to support their children and send them to college? And given the percentage of young adults who end up living at home with their moms and dads, are the parents coerced to take them in? In other words, do you think that American parents are turning their backs on their children?
The implication is that the Baby Boomers want it both ways: They had great jobs and enjoyed profligate lifestyles, and now that they’ve wrecked the economy they expect their poor kids to support the greedy geezers at their accustomed standard of living.
Baby Boomers aren’t all that bad, Andrew. They care about their children and they care about other young adults too. When the parents of the Baby Boomers get Alzheimer’s, dementia, or become too feeble to care for themselves, in general their kids have taken care of them – without “coercion.” There have been plenty of Baby Boomers who have faced hard times, even before the financial mess. The primary cause of bankruptcy for Baby Boomers was overwhelming medical bills.
Yes, many of us are facing challenging financial and economic problems, but please, let’s not talk about simplistic notions of who’s being “coerced.” Let’s not perpetuate the notion that young adults should feel resentment for the generation that raised them. Instead, let’s be constructive and get down to the business of figuring out what we need to do for all the generations.
Steve Sedio
Jun 4 2014 at 1:53pm
IMO, there are three very different factors at play.
Technology has made starting and running a company far easier than in the past. Transaction costs have fallen, allowing companies with almost no vertical integration (sorry Coase).
The world is getting better and better for those with the skills and required risk tolerance.
But, each labor saving device makes us more productive, while reducing the need for productivity.
That reduces the opportunity for those without the skill or risk tolerance. The blue collar jobs of the past are going away due to technology.
But, that is only part of the unemployment story.
Megan is right, when all those around you are unemployed, it is pretty easy to go along with the crowd. Unless you are starving to death, and have to move in with someone that is working, that requires you find a job.
But, in our rush to compassion, we have let the left demonize employers. Anyone working has to earn minimum wage, so the unskilled can’t get on the job training. Anyone working more than 32 hours gets expensive benefits – so we have a lot of part time jobs. Obamacare will stop many small companies from breaking the 50 employee barrier (so much for the rescue from small companies growing).
One would think these are unintended consequences, maybe. How many politicians keep getting re-elected by votes from supporting programs for the poor?
Programs that eliminate the need to move in with someone that is working, that requires you find a job.
The culture problem is of our own creation.
Back to those without the skill and risk tolerance. If you have the skill, you can let the entrepreneurs provide the risk tolerance. Where does the skill problem come from? For too many, our education system is horrible. The culture problem detailed above exacerbates the problems in K-12. School has no value if there are no jobs, and if no one is hounding you about how you did on this or that test (how many get good grades).
K-12 has a more important role than just education, it teaches work ethic (or it is supposed to – what is being said about Millenials?).
Beyond that, education has disconnected from the labor market. Many graduate from college with degrees with no associated job opportunities. Get a degree that gets you a decent paying job you can tolerate, then go back to school to pursue your passion(s).
Why is this time different. IMHO, because huge productivity gains have allowed us to support a large un / under employed population.
Socialism is working because capitalism is working. When capitalism collapses, socialism will follow. And, it won’t be a gentle collapes.
Steven
Jun 4 2014 at 9:00pm
Steve, welcome! I agree with some of your comments, but it would be boring for me to focus on what we agree on. For the sake of brevity and interest, I’m going to hit you with questions about certain points.
Steve wrote: “in our rush to compassion, we have let the left demonize employers.”
I don’t agree, either about the “rush to compassion” or the “we” who is allowing the Left to demonize employers. To be sure, there is plenty of political rhetoric that demonizes, coming from all parties and sides. I would agree that the public allows, and even encourages, far too much rhetoric, partly because the mainstream news media encourages it. But let’s not pretend that such rhetoric is only coming from one side.
Steve wrote: “Anyone working has to earn minimum wage, so the unskilled can’t get on the job training.”
Steve, I’m an engineer, and I have received plenty of very expensive on-the-job training in my career. Ah, but you’re talking about unskilled labor. So let’s consider that. Please give me a real world example of the sort of job that an unskilled worker would receive on-the-job training for if only companies didn’t have to pay minimum wage. What kinds of jobs are those, anyway? Is there any data to indicate what percentage of companies aren’t able to hire workers they actually need because the minimum wage is too high?
You know, Steve, if I could pay people one dollar an hour to clean my house, pull my weeds, do my shopping, be my chauffeur, and give me a massage every day, I suppose I’d do that. I’d be a regular job creator.
And by the way, there are many businesses that offer volunteer internships, in which the worker is paid nothing and receives no benefits whatsoever, but they do receive on-the-job training. Not to mention all the people who perform volunteer work for the sake of training and experience, and the hope of getting a foot in the door of a paying job. Not to mention all the people who do part-time and temp work for the same reasons.
Steve wrote: “Anyone working more than 32 hours gets expensive benefits”
Yes, “expensive benefits” is code for medical benefits. Okay Steve, please drop the other shoe, because I’m all ears. I would agree that we have a crazy approach to basic medical care in this country. I’m not going to defend the current system. But if people who work don’t receive, or can’t afford, health care, what do we do about that “expensive” problem? Telling us it’s an impediment to employers is simply sweeping the issue under the rug. How about we let employers completely off the hook for medical benefits? And then what?
Steve wrote: “K-12 has a more important role than just education, it teaches work ethic”
I think education is tremendously important, but we shouldn’t expect teachers to have primary responsibility for instilling a “work ethic” in our children. Neither should we put too high an expectation for them to be “super teachers” who are super inspirational. The expectation should be on the kids to take education seriously, and to behave in a civil and disciplined manner. Teachers can’t be expected to compensate for the failings of the parents and the society.
Steve wrote: “Why is this time different. IMHO, because huge productivity gains have allowed us to support a large un / under employed population.”
It’s amazing what societies can support and afford when there is a will to do so. The US can somehow afford two expensive and unnecessary wars, an expensive Medicare Part D expansion, and a looming military presence throughout the world (to name a few), around the same time we had tax cuts. In the 1920s, Germany was an economic mess and yet in a short time, due to “productivity gains,” it managed to offer a serious threat to the world order. What if Germany had used that energy and zeal in other ways? How long did it take Japan (South Korea, etc.) to create first-class economies?
I don’t know any economist who claims that our current level of productivity would allow us to sustainably support a large un/underemployed population. Indeed, I hear the opposite. Every economist I’ve read and heard seems to think that we still need a lot more good jobs in order to sustain a viable middle class.
Steve wrote: “Socialism is working because capitalism is working.”
Okay, I suppose you’re saying that we have to have a healthy economy in order to afford social welfare programs. Steve, are you implying that some economists think we can have socialism without capitalism? Are you making any distinctions between social welfare programs and socialism? Do you think we should completely eradicate all government social welfare programs and leave it all to, say, charities? Again, please drop the other shoe; otherwise it just sounds like talking points.
anonman
Jun 5 2014 at 12:37am
To Steve,
Socialism does work. There are very few limited examples, like Isthmus, but they are there. The problem is that there are different examples of socialism and that people don’t parse the variances of the term. You’re talking about democratic socialism or worse, and that’s bad, but can also do good.
Capitalism is a natural system. Socialism is also natural to an extent, but is a little harder to pull off. To the extent that we’re talking about logical socialism, the only thing that matters is the measurement of money. In that regard, if it functions much the same way as capitalism, so be it.
Socialism in terms of worker ownership of the means of production and co-ops really only works, however, with higher-skilled workers who are in a firm for a longer time with real vested interest in the outcome of everything. In other words, socialism often doesn’t work or will not work because of TURNOVER. It’s really no more complicated than that. For all the people looking for a deeper reason why socialism doesn’t work or who call certain things socialism without any understanding of what they are, they need look no further at all.
I love capitalism and respect capitalists. Workers under the ‘thumb’ of capitalists are getting a sweetheart deal. They must get paid, no matter what, and their finances are not on the line really at all.
Much of the problem with the left demonizing capitalists lies with obvious atrocities, like the Waltons earning billions a year in dividends for doing nothing. If you get rid of that, people like me will look around and understand capitalism to be a wonderful system.
I also don’t argue with you about the terrible circumstance of capitalists being forced to pay you before you are productive. Being a worker myself, I would absolutely love for that to be eliminated. But that period of no pay should only last a short time. I want everyone to succeed, including my employer, and the state wants the worker to succeed. We can arrange better circumstances together.
anonman
Jun 5 2014 at 12:53am
I feel compelled to comment again, since I loved the feedback from others.
I am also deeply concerned about the way McAfee bloviates about technology. I’ve heard a number of his talks on Youtube and they are all pretty much the same. And in the end, most of the conclusions tend to be that the future will be wildly different, but no REAL policy recommendations. To the uninitiated, this is probably a good discussion, but the younger generation is infatuated with technology already and they know the gist.
And anyway, even though I am a mild techno-utopian, I always offer an anchor back to reality. AI doesn’t really matter to me that much, since it will probably only really mean better ways to sell stuff to people, which capitalism is bloated with already. All the other aspects of technology? Well, they are cool to speculate about, but I don’t care about Moore’s law AT ALL. Computers are fast enough, thank you. That’s just the beginning of my criticism. I could also talk about the uselessness of cyborg-mania, which is not only preposterous, but not desirable. Ray Kurzweil probably intuitively understands the ridiculousness of half his claims, but it sells to the gullible.
How about how the whopper that technology increases unemployment and inequality and will become worse with AI? Well, it’s not really a whopper, but must be said with a giant asterisk. Inequality is increasing because YOU CAN SERVE SO MANY MORE PEOPLE THAN BEFORE. Come back to reality more often, and realize that our problems are far more mundane than naked speculation about amorphous technological advances and the wild-card future of AI.
Furthermore, at times, I AM a Luddite. I fell out of love with my phone a while ago and prefer conversation better. I also don’t see any benefit for new online games and social networks if there is next to zero policy for public programs and government public projects, like infrastructure for public space and physical, civic realms of engagement, a quality our nation is sorely lacking. We need quality-of-life improvements, desperately.
Also, the knowledge economy is basically Communism. We need to think about building up living arrangements in the future so that people will work for the love of it if there is no logical reason to force homelessness if no one is building a car-free society or building the next Farmville.
I really think that the government needs to be far more heavily involved in infrastructure-building, but not only physical things. Networks, platforms, etc., just like Charles Marohn suggested, so that people know they are building on to something that makes sense. A society without goals is like a rudderless ship, and capitalism can be a giant mishmash of chaos with no real form. I believe that markets should be shaped, liked Stiglitz, so that great things can grow up around the frame, but the government hasn’t been doing a great job with the framing aspect.
The future will be different, but there is no reason to specifically believe that it must happen under oppression. In the article, ‘Breezily Apocolyptic’, it mentions many of the ideas of silicon valley that are not always meant to make money, but to serve people and increase community ties, or the sharing economy. This is my main concern. We can do so much better if our economy has people working for different reasons than profit, because in a zero-marginal cost society, profit will be harder to come by. This is basically the logical conclusions of the ramblings of Karl Marx.
Steven
Jun 5 2014 at 1:26am
Thanks for the comments, anonman. Worker ownership and co-ops of certain businesses as a kind of socialism? I’ll have to think about that.
People who work for capitalists get paid, as long as they have a job. I suppose the “risk” for a worker is the risk of losing a job when he has expenses and debt. Maybe I didn’t put that quite clearly: When people decide to work for a business, and they have an expectation of a salary, they begin to take on certain “risks” that depend on that salary. For example, they get married, have kids, buy a car and a house; in other words they take on expenses and debt. They are supporting themselves and they often have dependents. To me, that is a kind of risk, and in a very real sense an employee’s finances are “on the line.” There is no lack of employees filing for bankruptcy. Employee risk may not be the same level of risk as the capitalist business owner, but then, the business owner might be making a lot more money than his workers. Indeed, it would be a strange case if a business owner made less than his employees.
Regarding the lack of productivity of new employees, there’s nothing new about that. A couple of weeks ago I had an interesting discussion with a supervisor at a customer service organization. She was proud of the fact that her company trained each new employee for six full weeks, with pay. I’m sure that a large portion of that training involved very specific product knowledge, not the kind of knowledge that would be universally transferrable to other jobs, even in customer service. Or, consider the training required for someone to work at a fast food restaurant. Again, the skills are very specific. Is it onerous to expect the capitalist owners to pay people while undergoing the training required to do their job? If a business owner can’t afford to pay employees while they are being trained to do tasks that are specific to the job, what does that say about the financial viability of that business?
anonman
Jun 5 2014 at 3:13am
Yeah, I was going to mention that specifically. An employee’s benefit is going to have to be thought out in the longer term, in terms of cost-benefit analysis, whether he or she is going to retain the job or not, but that is not the same level of immediate consequence of being able to make payroll for the employees of a specific firm.
I work for a small business right now. The owner is quite benevolent. He does not like to think of his roll as a capitalist, but as a provider of benefits to those who are committed to his (long-standing, and knowledgeable company) long-term service. He will take the benefits off of his company in the long term, provided he is able to provide knowledge that is not easily obtained by workers who are not committed and will not provide benefits to other workers themselves.
My personal capitalist employer has been profitable for ten years and only has lost money for the last two. Even though I have only been able to work for him for a summer, I already understand his mindset. I do not wish for him to fail any more than I would wish for myself to succeed under him.
He has lost his house, at least currently. This is a huge risk, and is one of the reasons that capitalism is so successful, being that real people are under real pressure to perform.
I do not clock in under all hours of work for this reason, being that capitalists must perform UNDER THE LAW, and I will not ever seek retribution for lack of pay.
I am constantly concerned though about HIS situation, since I know that the American Dream is so expensive. And since I am so young, part of me thinks that I don’t deserve the dream any more than he does at this moment.
Capitalism is complicated and will require some people to sacrifice during the times that others are prosperous, since capitalism is a massive game of arbitrage; you do not make money, you take it.
But as a worker, I will not complain for now, as it requires, more than other systems, patience and stages of cultural age-acceptance, being that capitalism is so closely linked to our cultural system; it perfectly denotes our spending habits, which are closely related with age, after all.
I have had too many examples to relate to you, even after these short two months.
Capitalism is not perfect at all, but solves too many problems to relate to you right at this moment.
Russ must be pleased, but he should not get this into his head.
In other comments, I have related to you all where capitalism has failed miserably. This is not something to be forgotten, because capitalism has major shortcomings, but is not something that says we should throw it all out at once.
Graham
Jun 5 2014 at 9:17am
I would like to propose a new “occupation” for analysis: protesting.
Say unemployed people have two options:
1) improve employment prospects (look for a job, go to school, network, start a company, etc). Getting a job provides access to income and consumption
2) protest (campaign on the streets or online for more government redistribution). Redistribution provides income and consumption
It could be that this individual’s optimal return on their invested time & effort is option 2. As technology eliminates low-skilled jobs, maybe the set of people for whom option 2 is optimal increases over time. Maybe protesting is the job of the future. Just a thought.
Shawn Barnhart
Jun 5 2014 at 11:41am
There was some discussion during the panel by I think Megan about highly skilled, traditional blue collar jobs that pay well with good benefits finding difficulty getting workers — the people who could do these jobs (decent education, math capable, etc) are choosing Starbucks while they wait for a white collar job.
One thing not mentioned was why nobody wants to take these jobs. I’m educated, math capable and I think a highly skilled blue collar work would probably be at least as interesting as my IT job, which truth be told is largely the white collar equivalent of a millwright.
The problem isn’t the work or the compensation, it’s the treatment of the workers by management. These jobs are still stuck in the dictatorial, worker-hostile mindset of blue collar labor of nearly a century ago. Partly this is the result of the longstanding union/labor structure, but I think a lot of is cultural. I’d much rather work in a white collar environment for less money where there’s some dignity and flexibility afforded rather than the fairly harsh labor practices employed towards blue collar employees.
Fix the cultural mindset that says a person who can barely operate a computer for word processing deserves better treatment than the person who can tear down and repair a computer-driven machine tool and you’ll go a long way towards improving the labor market.
Antonio
Jun 5 2014 at 11:52am
I, for one, want to hear more from the panel members on dealing with the problems of culture that Mrs. McArdle raised as critical determinants of economic outcomes, micro and macro. Indeed, this is a topic that receives only glancing attention on EconTalk (I’m still a pleased, long-time listener though!).
I recognize that it is a subjective matter, but it’s also something of an elephant in the room that the second we cede that culture matters apropos of economic outcomes, we are implicitly inviting the postmodernists to the discussion who will bring nothing but accusations of white/male/cis privilege and/or Marxist rhetoric. Given the recent outcomes of the Brendan Eich and Donald Sterling affairs, as well as $15 minimum wages and Obama raising the federal minimum wage, it’s in the air (unequivocally so here in Seattle, where I live) that the lefty agenda of a most vaguely defined “equality qua summum bonum” is thoroughly permeating and influencing the national consciousness.
That We Anglo-Americans, the alleged champions of the Western tradition, seemingly refuse to acknowledge that a “correct” culture is necessary but insufficient to achieve the healthy outcomes of capitalism is extremely disconcerting. Let any academic, politician, or celebrity state it plainly as that, however, and they’ll be hanged in the public gallows with no compunction e.g. Bill Cosby.
To be perfectly clear, I do believe that culture matters vis-a-vis economic outcomes, but I’m extraordinarily worried by this cultural/institutional position between and rock and hard place in which we find ourselves.
All that said, I also feel far too young to be this anxious about a topic such as this, haha.
Steve Sedio
Jun 5 2014 at 9:42pm
Steven wrote: “I would agree that the public allows, and even encourages, far too much rhetoric, partly because the mainstream news media encourages it.”
IMO politicians encourage it as well. So many people are willing to look for the simple answer (improving education needs more money & smaller class sizes), rather than do the studies, set up experiments and find out what really works. The politicians & media are bought by special interests. For education, the teachers union doesn’t want change, especially if the results are impressive, because then they have to explain why they (the experts) let things drift so far off.
Steven wrote: “Please give me a real world example of the sort of job that an unskilled worker would receive on-the-job training for if only companies didn’t have to pay minimum wage.”
Many of the trades, plumber, electrician, machinist, auto mechanic, heavy equipment operator are jobs that used to start as an apprentice. The employee starts out doing the simple, dirty jobs, then spend progressively more time learning / doing the job that requires skill. Those that require education (I know of machinists that need calculus), go to night school.
Steven wrote: “But if people who work don’t receive, or can’t afford, health care, what do we do about that “expensive” problem?”
Health care is expensive because there is no direct link between the cost of care, and what the patient pays. My company pays $15K a year for my families coverage – how many people know what their employer pays? How many know what the medication costs beyond the co-pay.
The solution is for us to pay out of pocket. The problem is the prices have drifted so high that someone paying out of pocket (or buying their own insurance) is stunned.
My suggestion, we change insurance to pay anything above a certain monthly amount. That way all patients start shopping. Providers that can lower costs capture market share, pushing other providers to cost reduce. In time, the market will work, and costs will fall. The key is over time. The government solution of fixed pricing will reduce (has reduced) providers, and degrade service.
The “subsidized care act” is doing nothing to reduce total costs.
Steven wrote: “The expectation should be on the kids to take education seriously, and to behave in a civil and disciplined manner.”
Sorry, that isn’t the real world any more.
The education problem is the response to the job problem. Why waste time in an inner city school, when most of the adults you know don’t work, or have jobs that don’t need education.
You want kids (and kids parents) to want to go to school, create a suitable benefit.
Steven wrote: “It’s amazing what societies can support and afford when there is a will to do so.
Are we paying for the wars now? Had there been a vote to increase taxes by $700B, would it have passed?
The ability to borrow money has screwed u our politics.
Steve wrote: “Steve, are you implying that some economists think we can have socialism without capitalism?”
It doesn’t matter what economists think. Keynes has been dusted off yet again to justify throwing money at any number of problems.
In the podcast, infrastructure was touted as a need. In some cases, but politicians don’t run ROI’s, and they see infrastructure as a method of getting votes.
The proponents of socialism I take to think market socialism is the ticket – supposedly all the benefits of the free market, but without the capitalism. Supposedly buy ownership (your job), and vote on management.
How exactly does entrepreneurship work? Who is going to buy a job at a start up?
Without creation, you get stagnation – even own a 1960’s automobile…..
And I agree, both side of the political spectrum are at fault.
Steven
Jun 5 2014 at 11:21pm
Wow, a lot of comments.
Anonman, I don’t know anyone who doesn’t “sacrifice” for their employer or company. Everyone I know does plenty of work for no pay. This is nothing new.
Graham, I’m not sure if your “thought” is meant to be humorous?
Shawn, I think it’s a myth that employers are having difficulty finding people to fill good-paying, high-skill blue collar jobs. But I’m interested in the evidence for that claim if anyone’s got a reference to it.
Antonio, I share your interest in more discussions about “culture.”
I have multiple points to address with Steve.
Yes, politicians are especially prolific and proficient at rhetoric.
Steve wrote: “Many of the trades, plumber, electrician, machinist, auto mechanic, heavy equipment operator are jobs that used to start as an apprentice.”
Yes, and those professions still have apprenticeships, they are still very profitable, and they pay their apprentices. I’m looking for examples of the types of businesses that can’t afford to train people at minimum wage.
Steve wrote: “Health care is expensive because there is no direct link between the cost of care, and what the patient pays.”
Okay, that’s a fair point, but now you’ve got to drop the other shoe. Let’s take an extreme case and maximize that “direct link” by eliminating insurance altogether. If people need medical care, they must pay out of pocket, either by cash or credit card. All of a sudden, most of the people who need medical care the most will not be able to afford it. I suppose, theoretically, prices would come down somewhat. But I think it would still be very expensive. People are willing to pay a lot of money to relieve their suffering or to save their lives. People with infections and chronic diseases, such as diabetes, might avoid getting medical care. So, in other words, a “direct link” sounds good, but how would it work? Medical expenses are the primary cause of bankruptcy in America, even for people who have jobs and medical insurance, and it’s not as if we haven’t had millions of people who haven’t had medical insurance, who were “paying out of pocket.” If someone (adult or child) is unlucky enough to get cancer, or get injured, and treatment costs over a hundred thousand dollars, do we tell those people to pay out of pocket or die?
I think we have to think a bit harder about a for-profit model for medical care. I may be wrong, but I think a for-profit system, unfettered, is bound to be expensive, with or without insurance. If anyone can recommend a good book that makes the case for the superiority of a for-profit health care system, please tell me about it.
Steve wrote: “Sorry, that isn’t the real world any more.”
Sorry, but if that is really true, if you really believe that, if you think it’s impossible to change our culture so kids take education seriously and behave in a civil and disciplined manner, then all hope is lost. Game over.
Steve wrote: “Why waste time in an inner city school?”
We need to discuss solutions that eliminate “inner cities” (i.e. ghettos). We need to move in that direction. I call that civilization and progress. We’ve made quite a bit of progress over the past several thousand years. Why should I believe that we can’t continue to make progress?
Steve wrote: “Are we paying for the wars now? Had there been a vote to increase taxes by $700B, would it have passed?”
Well, yes, in some very real ways we have been paying for those wars. If your point is that much of the financial costs have been put on the credit card, that’s true, and we’ll keep on paying. If there had been a vote to increase taxes to pay for the wars, perhaps we wouldn’t have gone to war? Now there’s a thought.
Steve wrote: “It doesn’t matter what economists think.”
I’m sorry, but I don’t think that’s a useful answer. Even if you think it’s true, if you’re going to make an assertion you need to support it, if for no other reason than to help me understand the point you’re trying to make.
Steve wrote: “The proponents of socialism I take to think market socialism is the ticket – supposedly all the benefits of the free market, but without the capitalism.”
Again I’m sorry, but I don’t know what that means.
anonman
Jun 7 2014 at 10:02pm
Market socialism is the free market, meaning buying and selling, according to the principle of consumer sovereignty, but practiced with a different ownership structure of a certain business. Not really different from capitalism all that much, really. The state does not own anything, only individuals, and instead of proprietorship or a partnership, you would have a multiplicity of ownership.
anonman
Jun 8 2014 at 12:27am
By the way, it cannot be emphasized enough that the difference between a corporation and market socialism is that the workers under market socialism actually work for the company and are not absentee. Capitalism, and hence, the corporation, are largely exploitative and merely ways to prevent inflation. Just because you’ve made money in the past under capitalism, doesn’t mean you should be the only one to be able to invest in the company in the present.
Seth
Jun 9 2014 at 2:51pm
Re: Just after the 34 minute mark, McAfee’s comments about ‘Walmart types of jobs” and whether regulation or cultural pressure is best to change these jobs to be less exploitative and jobs that of which McAfee approves. Personal preference bias.
There seems to be little interest on McAfee’s part to entertain the idea the these jobs fit different situations.
It’s like saying, travelling by Greyhound is undesirable to me, so we either need to outlaw Greyhound or pressure them into offering modes of transportation of which I approve. Which is best? Never considering that the folks who choose Greyhound have their reasons.
Steven
Jun 9 2014 at 4:22pm
Seth, I think we have to be careful about what we mean by “undesirable.” People aren’t trying to earn a living by traveling on buses. What are you trying to say? A Greyhound bus ride is like a job that doesn’t pay the bills, and a middle class job is a limousine?
If we’re going to talk in terms of what is “undesirable” and “desirable,” wouldn’t you agree that jobs that pay well enough to enable people not to require government welfare are desirable? Do you imagine that only McAfee “approves” of decent jobs?
SaveyourSelf
Jun 10 2014 at 11:53pm
@Russ ~[31:35] “McAfee: Oh, come on, did you walk through a sea of pleasant experiences in the airports on your way here? … Russ: That’s an outlier… McAfee: When you call up Comcast… Russ: Also an outlier…You’ve picked the example of the places in America where there is very little competition due to regulation and government monopoly.”
That was awesome. Truly one of those superstar, effortless, flawlessly executed moves you pull off every couple of episodes.
@ Andrew Mcafee ~ [3:03] you said, “The amount of information in digital form is increasing by many orders of magnitude, very regularly.”
You imply that the volume of data available is causally associated with improved standard of living. I have heard good arguments on econtalk that suggest the opposite can also be true–diminishing marginal returns and all. If you accept a slight alteration of your statement so that it reads, “The ease-of-access to information and the ability to filter through it are increasing by many orders of magnitude regularly,” then I think you will have a much stronger argument.
You also said, ~[3:03] “The challenge, though, is the challenge of distribution.” And [34:26] “How will those benefits be distributed?”
Dr. Mcafee, one of the principal functions of a market is rationing. Markets distribute. That is what they do. When you say that distribution is a challenge, I suspect it is because you are trying to think of ways to force the market to distribute in ways you, personally, find desirable. But the market already includes your desires as an input in its rationing, along with everyone else’s. To have a stronger influence on the outcome, you would have to somehow handicap everyone else or subsidize yourself. Either way, you would make the market LESS egalitarian and its output LESS optimal. You would literally be creating greater disparity in the distribution of resources.
You display a similar misunderstanding of the free-market model when you say, “the serious issues are insecurity and the inability to either count on, as you say, understand what your future path looks like, that this is a job that I could actually have for a couple of years, that I can try to build a career and understand what that looks like, that I know I will have this job, that my employer views me as someone that they are not going to fire and let go.”
The market is a tool of rationing. When operating perfectly, markets’ change distribution with every additional piece of information. Efficient markets, therefore, are CONSTANTLY CHANGING. Constant change is, by definition, unpredictable. The predictability you seem to long for is actually a sign of an inefficient market. Inefficiency in markets is correlated with lower relative standards of living. In a very real sense, therefore, you’re longing for predictability and security is a longing for poverty and stagnation.
@Megan McArdle ~ [08:49] “You can think of culture as the operating system for the hardware that’s underneath. Culture is what makes markets work.”
That is a fascinating take on culture. It works for me.
You also said, “…part of what is contributing to that cycle if we do not intervene, is that people at the bottom with their paths disrupted by work, are not able to sustain a culture of work.”
I think you have made a mistake here. You do not appear to consider the time and effort spent farming for handouts as work. From an individual perspective, begging–or any of its equivalent variations–is work. Granted, from a societal perspective, begging is not productive but for the individual, it counts. This distinction is important at low income levels where these two forms of work are substitutes for one another. Viewed in this way, the cycle-of-poverty may be causally associated with either inadequate rewards for productive-work OR excessively large rewards for work that is not-productive. The former, when viewed in isolation, places the fault of the cycle-of- poverty in the price mechanism—ie, the free market. The latter, when viewed in isolation, places the fault of the cycle of poverty on the fool who is willing to pay someone for work which he does not consider productive—ie. Socialism. Importantly, which side of this scale you choose to intervene on matters. Dismantling the price mechanism means dismantling the market which means reducing the overall standard-of-living for all market participants which means increasing poverty. On the other hand, reducing handouts drives more people in to the markets. Since the markets are the greatest tool for increasing standard-of-living we have ever discovered, increased utilization of markets is predictably associated with an increase in standard-of-living and a decrease in poverty.
So when you said, ”…that’s the sad, depressing future work stuff, where we are not raising the kids who are capable of being the workers that we need.”
What you ought to be saying—based on my previous argument—is that, ”the sad, depressing truth is we are paying people to specialize in skill-sets that are not productive to society. And the fact that we keep paying them over time to continue those activities produces a cycle-of-poverty.”
KEvin Smith
Jun 16 2014 at 9:21am
This was a great discussion.
It seems that a few times in the panel there were people predicting a future with less work and wondering why men in lower class communities play video games instead of get jobs.
Those men are simply the forefront of the coming future. They have little incentive to get married since they have access to sex and fatherhood without it, they have little incentive to work – the marginal gain over the work/welfare of their wife/girlfriend is too small. It seems instead of worrying about why men make this choice or if “women could demand more of them” – I think someone said, we should just understand they are acting rational in the current economic and moral framework of our society. If I was poor and uneducated, why would I do more than play video games and move around from woman to woman. Society is not offering me alot to do more.
Randy
Jun 19 2014 at 11:46am
In Ms. McArdle’s first comments, she does a great job of describing how a more inclusive culture can benefit children raised in non-traditional and broken homes. However, her causes for disparity are reminiscent of former Senator Moynihan’s comments in his essay “The Negro Family: The Case for National Action.” These are difficult subjects to address and, clearly, prior and current policies fail to have an impact. Extreme prudence must be taken when attempting to alter family structures via government policy.
Comments are closed.